Adam Smith The Wealth Of Nations

ISBN 13: 9781857150117

The Wealth Of Nations

3,88 valoración promedio
( 23.030 valoraciones por Goodreads )
 
9781857150117: The Wealth Of Nations
Ver todas las copias de esta edición ISBN.
 
 

A book about economics which provides a comprehensive analysis of industrial economies. It offers an exposition of Smith's two great liberal principles of self-interest and natural liberty. This edition includes books one to four and an introduction to Smith's economic theories.

"Sinopsis" puede pertenecer a otra edición de este libro.

Extrait:

moFrom the introduction by Robert Reich

Adam Smith's ideas fit perfectly with this new democratic, individualistic idea. To him, the "wealth" of a nation wasn't determined by the size of its monarch's treasure or the amount of gold and silver in its vaults, nor by the spiritual worthiness of its people in the eyes of the Church. A nation's wealth was to be judged by the total value of all the goods its people produced for all its people to consume. To a reader at the start of the twenty-first century, this assertion may seem obvious. At the time he argued it, it was a revolutionary democratic vision.

Smith was born in 1723, in the small Scottish port of Kirkcaldy, which sits across the Firth of Forth from Edinburgh. His father was a collector of customs—a job that literally embodied the old mercantilist philosophy that Smith would later argue against. He was educated at the University of Glasgow, whose professors passionately debated the new concepts of individualism and ethics (one of his teachers, Francis Hutcheson, was prosecuted by the Scottish Presbyterian church for spreading the "false and dangerous" doctrines that moral goodness could be obtained by promoting happiness in others and that it was possible to know good and evil without knowing God), and then at Oxford, whose professors didn't debate or teach much of anything. In fact, the lassitude of Oxford's dons prompted Smith to suggest, in The Wealth of Nations, that professors be paid according to the number of students they attract, thereby motivating them to take a more lively interest in teaching—one of Smith's few suggestions with which today's tenured professors of economics generally disagree.

In 1748 Smith returned to the University of Glasgow, first as a professor of logic and then of moral philosophy, filling Francis Hutcheson's chair. There he published The Theory of Moral Sentiments in 1759, which brought him instant fame. In it, Smith asked how a normal self-interested person is capable of making moral judgments, when the essence of morality is selflessness. It was a question that troubled many of the new thinkers of the eighteenth century, who had liberated themselves from both theology and codes of aristocratic or chilvaric virtue. Smith's answer foreshadowed Sigmund Freud's superego: People possess within themselves an "impartial spectator" who advises them about moral behavior.

Smith resigned his professorship in 1764 to become tutor to the son of the late Duke of Buccleuch. The boy's mother, Countess of Dalkeith, had just remarried Charles Townshend, one of Smith's many admirers, who later became Britain's chancellor of the exchequer, and was responsible for imposing the taxes on the American colonies that prompted some Bostonians to throw large quantities of tea into Boston Harbor. For the next two years, Smith traveled throughout the Continent, beginning work on the book that was to become The Wealth of Nations. He visited Voltaire in Geneva, and in Paris met François Quesnay, a physician in the court of Louis XV who had devised a chart of the economy—a "tableau economique" he called it—showing the circulation of products and money in an economy analogous to the flow of blood through a body. Quesnay and his fellow Physiocrats believed that wealth came from a nation's production that enlarged the flow rather than from its accumulation of gold and silver, as the prevailing mercantilists believed, and that governments should therefore remove all impediments to the flow of money and goods in order to increase production.
Smith took these notions to heart, although he didn't agree with everything the Physiocrats propounded (such as their view that agricultural production was the only true source of wealth). Returning to Glasgow in 1766, he spent the better part of the following decade working out his theories. Occasionally he'd travel to London to discuss them with luminaries such as the philosopher Edmund Burke, historian Edward Gibbon, Benjamin Franklin (visiting from America), and the remarkable personalities Samuel Johnson and James Boswell. Smith's book finally appeared on March 9, 1776, in two volumes, and went through several subsequent editions. It was well received, although not an immediate sensation. Smith spent his remaining years back in Edinburgh as commissioner of customs, the same kind of mercantilist sinecure his father had held, and died in July 1790, at the age of sixty-seven.

The Wealth of Nations is resolutely about human beings—their capacities and incentives to be productive, their overall well-being, and the connection between productivity and well-being. In the very first sentence of his Introduction, Smith takes aim at the mercantilists and declares, "The annual labour of every nation is the fund which originally supplies it with all the necessaries and conveniences of life. . . ." And two paragraphs later he states that a nation's wealth grows because of "the skill, dexterity, and judgment with which its labour is generally applied. . . ." Smith's concern about all of a nation's working people is evident. In a wealthy nation "a workman, even of the lowest and poorest order, if he is frugal and industrious, may enjoy a greater share of the necessaries and conveniences of life than it is possible for any savage to acquire." In the rest of the book he explains why this is so.
While The Theory of Moral Sentiments showed how normal, self-interested people could make moral judgments by consulting an internal "impartial spectator," in The Wealth of Nations Smith explains how such people will automatically contribute to the well-being of others even absent such consultations, simply by pursuing their own ends. "It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner," writes Smith, in one of the most frequently cited passages in the history of economic thought, "but from their regard to their own interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but to their self-love. . . ." With several strokes of his pen, Smith thereby provided a moral justification for motives that had been morally suspect in Western thought for thousands of years.

How can self-interested behavior—the "private interests and passions" of men Smith calls them—lead to the good of the whole? By means, he says, of an "invisible hand"—perhaps the most famous, or infamous, bodily metaphor in all of social science. By an "invisible hand" Smith does not mean a mystical force; he is referring to an unfettered market propelled both by competition among self-interested sellers and by buyers seeking the best possible deals for themselves. If sellers produce too little of something to meet buyers' demands, for example, the price of the product will rise until other sellers step in to fill the gap. If some sellers charge too high a price to begin with, others will step in and charge a lower one.

Unimpeded, the invisible hand will allocate goods efficiently. But the key to wealth creation, for Smith, comes in the division of labor—by which individuals specialize in doing or producing a particular thing. Smith famously illustrates this principle by reference to the making of pins within the kind of small factory that characterized the early years of the Industrial Revolution. "One man draws out the wire, another straights it, a third cuts it, a fourth points it, a fifth grinds it at the top for receiving the head; to make the head requires two or three distinct operations . . . ," he explains. "I have seen a small manufactory of this kind where ten men only were employed . . . [who] could make among them upwards of forty-eight thousand pins a day." He contrasts this with the likely output of individuals who tried to make the entire pins themselves. "[I]f they had all wrought separately and independently . . . they certainly could not each of them have made twenty, perhaps not one pin in a
day. . . ."

Specialization improves productivity because it allows workers to become more skilled in their specific tasks, motivates them to discover more efficient means of doing them, and saves them the time of changing over to different tasks. Here, Smith noticed something that modern managers often overlook: Innovation often begins with the workers closest to the things being worked upon. "A great part of the machines made use of in those manufactures in which labour is most subdivided, were originally the inventions of common workmen, who, being each of them employed in some simple operation, naturally turned their thoughts towards finding out easier and readier methods of performing it."

In order to reap the full benefits of specialization, the market must be sufficiently large. After all, there's little point in creating forty-eight thousand pins if there aren't enough people to buy them. The larger the market, the greater the opportunities for specialization. It follows that barriers to trade, within a nation or between nations—regulations, licenses, tariffs, quotas, and other market protections—reduce potential wealth. At the extreme, the necessity of self-sufficiency causes hardship, as in "the lone houses and very small villages which are scattered about in so desert a country as the Highlands of Scotland, [where] every farmer must be butcher, baker, and brewer for his own family."

Biographie de l'auteur:

Adam Smith (5 June 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish moral philosopher and a pioneer of political economy. One of the key figures of the Scottish Enlightenment, Adam Smith is best known for two classic works: The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759), and An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776). The latter, usually abbreviated as The Wealth of Nations, is considered his magnum opus and the first modern work of economics.

"Sobre este título" puede pertenecer a otra edición de este libro.

Comprar nuevo Ver libro

Gastos de envío: GRATIS
De Reino Unido a Estados Unidos de America

Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

Añadir al carrito

Otras ediciones populares con el mismo título

9780679424734: Mod Lib Wealth Of Nations (Modern Library)

Edición Destacada

ISBN 10:  0679424733 ISBN 13:  9780679424734
Editorial: Random House Inc, 1994
Tapa dura

9781604598919: The Wealth of Nations

Thrift..., 2009
Tapa blanda

9780226763743: Wealth of Nations (A phoenix book)

Univer..., 1977
Tapa blanda

9780679783367: The Wealth of Nations

Modern..., 2000
Tapa blanda

9781546928966: The Wealth of Nations Book 4: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.

Create..., 2017
Tapa blanda

Los mejores resultados en AbeBooks

1.

Adam Smith
Publicado por Everyman, United Kingdom (1991)
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Tapa dura Cantidad disponible: 1
Librería
The Book Depository
(London, Reino Unido)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman, United Kingdom, 1991. Hardback. Condición: New. Language: English. Brand new Book. Published in the same year as the American Declaration of Independence, The Wealth of Nations has had an equally great impact on the course of modern history. Adam Smith's celebrated defence of free market economics is notable also as one of the Enlightenment's most eloquent testaments to the sanctity of the individual in his relations to the state. Nº de ref. del artículo: AAZ9781857150117

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 15,66
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: GRATIS
De Reino Unido a Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

2.

Smith, Adam
Publicado por Everyman (1991)
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Tapa dura Cantidad disponible: 5
Librería
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman, 1991. Condición: New. 1991. New Ed. Hardcover. Published in the same year as the American Declaration of Independence, this book focuses on free market economics. Series: Everyman's Library Classics. Num Pages: 622 pages. BIC Classification: KCA. Category: (G) General (US: Trade). Dimension: 210 x 130 x 36. Weight in Grams: 702. . . . . . . Nº de ref. del artículo: V9781857150117

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 17,17
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: GRATIS
De Irlanda a Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

3.

Adam Smith
Publicado por Everyman, United Kingdom (1991)
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Tapa dura Cantidad disponible: 1
Librería
Book Depository International
(London, Reino Unido)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman, United Kingdom, 1991. Hardback. Condición: New. Language: English. Brand new Book. Published in the same year as the American Declaration of Independence, The Wealth of Nations has had an equally great impact on the course of modern history. Adam Smith's celebrated defence of free market economics is notable also as one of the Enlightenment's most eloquent testaments to the sanctity of the individual in his relations to the state. Nº de ref. del artículo: AAZ9781857150117

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 18,01
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: GRATIS
De Reino Unido a Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

4.

Smith, Adam
Publicado por Everyman
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Tapa dura Cantidad disponible: 5
Librería
Kennys Bookstore
(Olney, MD, Estados Unidos de America)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman. Condición: New. 1991. New Ed. Hardcover. Published in the same year as the American Declaration of Independence, this book focuses on free market economics. Series: Everyman's Library Classics. Num Pages: 622 pages. BIC Classification: KCA. Category: (G) General (US: Trade). Dimension: 210 x 130 x 36. Weight in Grams: 702. . . . . . Books ship from the US and Ireland. Nº de ref. del artículo: V9781857150117

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 18,14
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: GRATIS
A Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

5.

Adam Smith
Publicado por Everyman
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Tapa dura Cantidad disponible: 1
Librería
THE SAINT BOOKSTORE
(Southport, Reino Unido)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman. Hardback. Condición: New. New copy - Usually dispatched within 2 working days. Nº de ref. del artículo: B9781857150117

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 10,93
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: EUR 7,72
De Reino Unido a Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

6.

Adam Smith
Publicado por Everyman (1991)
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Tapa dura Cantidad disponible: 6
Librería
The Monster Bookshop
(Fleckney, Reino Unido)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman, 1991. Hardcover. Condición: New. BRAND NEW ** SUPER FAST SHIPPING FROM UK WAREHOUSE ** 30 DAY MONEY BACK GUARANTEE. Nº de ref. del artículo: mon0003051657

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 14,26
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: EUR 4,44
De Reino Unido a Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

7.

Adam Smith
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Cantidad disponible: 3
Librería
Speedy Hen LLC
(Sunrise, FL, Estados Unidos de America)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Condición: New. Bookseller Inventory # ST1857150112. Nº de ref. del artículo: ST1857150112

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 19,02
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: GRATIS
A Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

8.

Adam Smith
Publicado por Everyman's Library (1991)
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Tapa dura Cantidad disponible: 10
Librería
Ria Christie Collections
(Uxbridge, Reino Unido)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman's Library, 1991. Condición: New. book. Nº de ref. del artículo: ria9781857150117_rkm

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 15,31
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: EUR 4,31
De Reino Unido a Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

9.

Adam Smith
Publicado por Everyman (1991)
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Cantidad disponible: 10
Librería
Books2Anywhere
(Fairford, GLOS, Reino Unido)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman, 1991. HRD. Condición: New. New Book. Shipped from UK in 4 to 14 days. Established seller since 2000. Nº de ref. del artículo: F6-9781857150117

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 10,02
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: EUR 10,02
De Reino Unido a Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

10.

Smith, Adam
Publicado por Everyman's Library
ISBN 10: 1857150112 ISBN 13: 9781857150117
Nuevo Tapa dura Cantidad disponible: 4
Librería
WFL
(Holtsville, NY, Estados Unidos de America)
Valoración
[?]

Descripción Everyman's Library. Hardcover. Condición: New. 1857150112 Brand New ,Original Book , Direct from Source , Express 6-8 business days worldwide delivery. Nº de ref. del artículo: DG#IL173173

Más información sobre este vendedor | Contactar al vendedor

Comprar nuevo
EUR 17,91
Convertir moneda

Añadir al carrito

Gastos de envío: EUR 4,18
A Estados Unidos de America
Destinos, gastos y plazos de envío

Existen otras copia(s) de este libro

Ver todos los resultados de su búsqueda